domingo, 10 de fevereiro de 2013

Fundos de Investimento Moralmente Responsáveis

-

Quando você joga seu dinheiro em um fundo de investimento, geralmente você não tem a menor idéia de onde este dinheiro vai parar, só quer saber se tem retorno. O site Te Deum Laudamus me chama a atenção para a existência de fundos de investimentos moralmente responsáveis, fundos que procuram fazer de investimento em empresas que têm preocupação moral, por exemplo fogem de ramos de negócios relacionados  a aborto, a pornografia, ou fazem pesquisa com células embrionárias, etc. Há vários tipos de fundos deste tipo nos Estados Unidos e com diferentes idéias do que seja moral. E eles são diferentes de fundos "socialmente" responsáveis, que geralmente têm uma preocupação com o meio ambiente.

O site Te Deum Laudamus recomenda o fundo Ave Maria Mutual Funds. E mostra um entrevista com George Schwartz que gerencia este fundo no programa The World Over da rede de televisão católica EWTN. Schwartz é também autor do livro acima "Good Return: Making Money by Morally Responsible investing".


No vídeo do programa do último dia 31 de janeiro, a entrevista começa em 11:33,  o assunto sobre investindo moralmente surge em 21:03.

Vou traduzir apenas os pontos que Schwartz falou (não tenho tempo para traduzir toda a entrevista). Até o ponto 6, Schwartz fala de maneira geral da economia e dos tipos de investimentos, depois ele fala sobre como o fundo Ave Maria investe em empresas moralmente responsáveis.



1) O PIB americano caiu no último trimestre de 2012, mas os investidores devem olhar para o longo prazo não os últimos resultados da economia. No longo prazo a perspectiva é boa, não tão boa quanto se o Obama tivesse perdido, mas é boa.

2) O capitalismo ainda funciona e com todos os seus problemas não há outro sistema econômico melhor.

3) Há sempre profetas do apocalipse. Mas ninguém sabe do futuro.

4) O melhor investimento de hoje em dia é em ações, os títulos públicos americanos devem sofrer muito com a inflação que se aproxima.

5) Investimento em títulos públicos municipais nos Estados Unidos é uma boa porque não pagam impostos, mas também sofrerão com a inflação, melhor comprar com prazos curtos, 1 ou 2 anos.

6) Investir em ouro é investir contra o capitalismo, é pensar que o capitalismo irá desmoronar, não invista muito nisso.

7) Para investir em empresas, nós usamos um grupo de conselheiros católicos, que inclui muitos reconhecidos empresários católicos e também teólogos, como Michael Novak, grande teólogo  e escritor.

8) O aborto é a nossa preocupação número 1, qualquer empresa que apoie de qualquer forma direta ou indireta o aborto está fora dos nossos investimentos, não recebe nossos recursos do fundo. Mas também olhamos se a empresa é relacionada a pornografia ou a pesquisas de células embrionárias.

9) Também não vemos necessidade de investir em países como China, que tem péssimo histórico na defesa de direitos humanos.

10) O fundo Ave Maria, mesmo com toda a sua preocupação moral, tem uma das melhores performances no país.

---

Sensacional. Taí uma atividade que eu gostaria de fazer parte, podia usar melhor o que eu aprendi de economia, mantendo meus princípios católicos.
Não conheço nada parecido com isso no Brasil. Imagino o problema que seria criar um fundos de investimento moralmente responsável no Brasil. Mas é sempre uma ótima idéia.

Vou comprar o livro de Schwartz.


(Eu também publiquei este post em meu outro blog Thyself, O Lord, no qual trato de assuntos não apenas relacionados a economia)

terça-feira, 5 de fevereiro de 2013

Entrevista com Richard Aleman

-

Richard Aleman é um dos mais conhecidos defensores do Distributismo. Eu já tive a oportunidade de conversar com ele por email. A revista Gilbert Magazine publicou uma entrevista com ele. Achei que a revista poderia ter aprofundado mais a discussão, mas vale pela introdução que Aleman dar para distributismo.

Vou colocar aqui parte da entrevista, acessem o site da American Chesterton Society para ler o restante:


An Interview with Richard Aleman, Distributist

by Sean Dailey

In the current issue of Gilbert Magazine (Vol. 16, No. 3 – November/December 2012), we interviewed Richard Aleman to learn about his fascinating background, his first encounter with G.K. Chesterton, his work to promote Distributism, and his recent experience working with the Minnesota Catholic Conference to promote an amendment to define marriage as a union between one man and one woman. Scroll down to read the entire interview.

Richard Aleman is a contributing editor to Gilbert Magazine and the founder of the Distributist Review. His column on Distributism appears in every issue of Gilbert Magazine.


GM Please tell us about your background. You are a native of Spain, but you are not Spanish. And you also spent some of your upbringing in New York. And how does a non-Spaniard from Spain get into the Marines?

RA Yes, I am Catalonian, from a town founded by the Romans in the third century B.C. (Badalona). The Catalan culture developed during the Middle Ages and our language grew from the Provençal language. Catalonia eventually formed part of the Crown of Aragon and today we are an autonomous region of Spain with our own Parliament and president.
Most of my early life was spent between Barcelona and New York City. After I became a naturalized citizen, I joined the best outfit in the world— the United States Marine Corps.

GM When and where did you first encounter G.K. Chesterton—in America or Spain? And did you first read him in English or Spanish (or Catalan)?
RA In Spain. A friend of mine shipped a copy of Orthodoxy to my home in Barcelona, and reading the book was life-changing. Chesterton’s Orthodoxy is just what a growing boy needs, especially one struggling with family life and with an insatiable curiosity about the world and all that lies beyond. If you recall, Chesterton dedicated this book to his mother, which is apropos because during this period of in my life my mother was distancing herself from organized religion. I was beginning to see it as the only possible course that makes any sense.

GM You have pretty much dedicated your whole life to spreading the Church’s teaching on social justice, as articulated by Chesterton and his contemporaries. What did you first find so gripping about Distributism? About what Chesterton has to say about it?
RA Your question takes me back to a quote in Orthodoxy: “Of all horrible religions the most horrible is the worship of the god within,” reminds me of what Chesterton wrote in The Catholic Church and Conversion, “We do not really need a religion that is right where we are right. What we need is a religion that is right where we are wrong.” Whatever area of the faith, my goal is to think with the mind of the Church. We cannot embrace Christianity without dying to ourselves.
When I sunk my teeth into Distributism I found myself wrong about all that is right, and right about some things I intuitively knew were wrong. Something seemed wrong with the political Left and the Right. The short version is that socialism was counter-intuitive to me, a misplaced faith in government action. Capitalists were over-confident in the free market as the solution. Self-criticism led me to realize I suffered from tribalism, and Distributism woke me up.
Archbishop Chaput recently said it best: we are Catholics before Democrats or Republicans, and even before we are Americans. And the Church has been saying this all along. So have Chesterton and Belloc.

GM What is the most common objection you get from people when you try to explain Distributism to them?
RA Well, most Distributists are accused of being capitalists, socialists, or some combination of the two. Part of the reason is because most people have overly broad definitions of capitalism and socialism. Trade equals capitalism. Government intervention equals socialism. Chesterton once wrote that if capitalism means to earn a profit, then the communist is a capitalist. He also joked that in the minds of some people a “social drink” sounds like suspicious socialist behavior. To say unbridled competition is wrong means you are a socialist. To say private property is good is to be a capitalist.
We’ve sown the seeds, bore the fruit, and it is time to admit neither tastes very well.
All things considered, the economic and political crises have opened up the door to commonality among those who would otherwise disagree. More people are realizing that when cooperative businesses like Mondragon Cooperative are succeeding in a nation (Spain) with twenty-five percent unemployment, maybe those Distributists are on to something. So let’s sit down with progressives and conservatives and start a discussion about what we agree on, where we are, and where we ought to be in the future.
Both will tell you they prefer Main Street to Wall Street. They want capital and labor to be treated fairly. They are starting to realize the problem is both Big Business and Big Government. Progressives and conservatives like local, organic food production, momand- pop businesses, community banking, and accountable and accessible government, and so on. They care about their families and worry what the future is going to look like for their kids. The “hands off—it’s my body” or “hands off—it’s my wallet” approach to life is unsustainable and they know it.
There’s more, but I think that’s a great start.



quinta-feira, 24 de janeiro de 2013

Catolicismo e a Mente Burguesa

-

Interessante texto de Thomas Storck (foto acima), publicado na The Distributist Review, fala da contradição que existe entre a Doutrina Católica e a mente burguesa, que busca a urbanização (afastamento da natureza) e a padronização da produção, tornando o homem em máquina.

Catholics and the Bourgeois Mind


In 1935 Christopher Dawson published a wonderful article with the title “Catholicism and the Bourgeois Mind.”[1] His article seems more relevant to Catholics in North America today than ever, for we are confronted with more clearly demarcated cultural choices now than fifty, or even twenty years ago. Specifically, we see various subcultural groups espousing some of the ideas that Dawson considers a natural part of Catholic civilization, but, for the most part, these groups have no connection with the Church, are not aware of their sometimes profound sympathy with important elements of Catholic culture, and, more strange still, these groups and their way of life are rejected by otherwise zealous and orthodox Catholics. I will discuss this in more detail below, after a short summary of Dawson’s article.
Dawson begins by stating that bourgeois civilization and Catholic civilization are fundamentally opposed to each other. Today, though, our entire culture is permeated by bourgeois ideals, yet if we look back at an earlier age when the bourgeoisie were merely one element within society, we can discern the particular characteristics of the bourgeois mind, and see why that mind is so opposed to Catholicism.

Features of the Bourgeois Mind

The first feature of the bourgeois mind that Dawson notes is its urbanism.
It involves the divorce of man from nature and from the life of the earth. It turns the peasant into a minder of machines and the yeoman into a shopkeeper, until ultimately rural life becomes impossible and the very face of nature is changed by the destruction of the countryside and the pollution of the earth and the air and the waters.[2]
Secondly, the bourgeois spirit is characterized by a peculiar attitude toward economic life. Instead of having the love of the artist or the craftsman toward his work, the bourgeois regards the things he deals in as
external and impersonal. He sees in them only objects of exchange, the value of which is to be measured exclusively in terms of money. It makes no difference whether he is dealing in works of art or cheap ready-made suits: all that matters is the volume of the transactions and the amount of profit to be derived from them.[3]
Further, “the bourgeois is essentially a money maker, at once its servant and its master, and the development of his social ascendancy shows the degree to which civilization and human life are dominated by the money power.”[4] Dawson concludes his essay by explaining that a true Catholic civilization is dominated by a spirit of love, love for God, and expresses that love in vibrant art, music, and various other uneconomic means. Bourgeois civilization, on the other hand, will never rise above essentially worldly motives and maxims, such as “Honesty is the best policy,” etc.

Counterculture and Catholicism

Now I think that no one will fail to notice that certain of the traits mentioned by Dawson as unbourgeois and akin to Catholic culture are very much prized by certain groups in the United States today. I mean, of course, what is usually called the counterculture. The counterculture is not one single thing, but within it there are groups strongly emphasizing virtues such as the value of being close to “nature and… the life of the earth,” of not bringing about “the destruction of the countryside and the pollution of the earth and the air and the waters” and of having the attitude of the artist or craftsman toward one’s work. I think that it is very unfortunate that these people do not recognize their affinity with Catholic culture (an affinity manifested also on the pan of some by their attitude toward contraceptives, the government school system, cooperative economic enterprises, breast-feeding, etc.); this is a loss both for them and for us in the Church. They are deprived in the first place of the many benefits of membership in Christ’s Mystical Body, but also of the key to their critique of modern Western life; we are deprived of brothers in the Faith who have valuable things to teach us, but also of possible allies who could do much to help outflank our enemies, the secularists.
But there are only two ways these people could find out that Catholicism is their natural home. One is by reading about Catholic things: not only writers such as Dawson, Belloc and Chesterton, but even old manuals for Catholic parents which, e.g., recommended breast-feeding in the forties and fifties when almost no one was nursing her baby. But for numerous reasons few are going to discover these books. Even the most well-known are largely ignored by general establishment (bourgeois) culture, and unless they should come into contact with our Catholic subculture they will not even know that such a man as Dawson existed, much less what he had to say. Which brings me to the second way.
The other way these people of the counterculture could discover that Catholicism is their real home is by seeing that nearly all Catholics live lives which reject bourgeois values, and that there is a Catholic counterculture which militantly stands up for many of the values they hold dear, yet with more consistency and for more complete reasons. But, alas, where will they find such a body of Catholics? Of course, there are some groups that do exemplify all facets of Catholic culture, but they are not many. Rather, if they look towards Catholics in America they will likely see two groups, each engaged in articulating its vision of Catholicism, and each involved in a discussion of the many political, social and moral issues facing us today.
The first group is the heterodox neo-modernist clique, unfortunately so prevalent today. With them the people of the counterculture might at first feel some kinship, for the neo-modernists in general probably favor the counterculture in general, but only for the same reasons that non, Catholic secular liberals do; namely, because it is new, different, and (so they think) opposed to traditional Western civilization (by which they mean whatever was done and thought in 1955).
But were these heretics to take a good look at the counterculture (or at least at certain elements within it) I think they might be distressed at what they saw. So, though there doubtless is some fraternizing between liberal Catholics and counter-culturists, I think this is based on a superficial acquaintance by both parties as to the real aims of each group.
The other articulate group of Catholics in America is the one I am mainly concerned with here. This is the group which vehemently eschews dogmatic heterodoxy and adheres strongly to the Church’s magisterium. In addition to that, this group reads Catholic authors such as Dawson, Belloc and Chesterton. The members of this group, in many cases, attempt to steep themselves in Catholic culture and traditions. They are aware that there is a great gulf separating modern Western life from Catholic civilization. Yet, with some notable exceptions, members of this group sometimes seem to possess the bourgeois character to a greater degree than the population in general. They oppose, .e.g., not just the excesses of the environmentalists, but sometimes their entire cause; they tend to look upon the counterculture as useless, faddish, self-indulgent and eccentric, or at best utopian; too often they ally themselves with right-wing groups that are thoroughly bourgeois, that stand for laissez-faire capitalism and its concomitant attitudes and values. Only in their attitude toward contraception and their valuing of large families will there be found much of a bond with the counterculture. But why is this so? Why is it that these Catholics, who are in possession of the key to the correct critique of bourgeois culture, do not see the implications of that critique; while the counterculture intuits and feels the wrongness of certain things without any knowledge of the underlying principles of their rebellion?
As to the first of these questions, I think the answer has two parts. Orthodox Catholics very often reject things such as a craft approach to work and a concern for ecology, because those they see who promote these things in some cases also promote drugs, Eastern religion, unchastity, etc. Most people only with difficulty and a deliberate effort can separate in thought things they habitually see conjoined in fact. Yet it is perfectly possible for someone to believe some true things and some false things. And this is true of movements too; they can be in part right and in part wrong.
The second reason, I think, is simply that the way of life of most of the orthodox group of Catholics is so different from what the counterculture aspires to, that this strangeness creates a distrust and lack of sympathy. Since everyone living what is considered an ordinary life in the modern West is more or less thoroughly bourgeois (as Dawson points out), it is natural for orthodox Catholics, likewise leading this bourgeois existence, to see this kind of life as the norm. Age doubtless has something to do with it, since most people of a certain age were not affected by the experiences that produced the counterculture and have consequently little sympathy with it. And, as of this point, most people in the orthodox Catholic resistance, at least those who articulate its policies and goals, know of the counterculture only through reading.

What Can Be Done?

If the situation is generally as I suggest here, what can be done? Well, perhaps naively, I think we must begin both to evangelize the counterculture and enlighten our fellow Catholics. As the second begins to succeed, the first will be done more easily. Will it be easy to do the second? Probably not; yet really all it will take is to get them to pay attention to certain themes and passages in authors they already read. But I have greater hope that as more people whose formation was affected in a good way by the counterculture’s critique of American society attain positions of leadership or influence among orthodox Catholics, they will help cast off the present bourgeois associations and look to the counterculture, both to teach and to learn.


End Notes
1. Reprinted in Christopher Dawson, The Dynamlcs of World History (New York: Sheed and Ward, 1956) p.200-212.
2. Ibld., p. 202-203.
3. Ibld., p. 203.
4. Ibld., p. 204.

sexta-feira, 11 de janeiro de 2013

Lista de Leitura: Doutina Social da Igreja e Distributismo

-

Hoje descobri o que procurava há muito tempo: uma lista de leitura para Doutrina Social da Igreja e para o Distributismo (que pode ser considerado a teoria econômica da Igreja). Devo isto ao site da The Distributive Review.

Vou guardar a lista aqui para mim e para vocês. Vai que perco este site..Aliás, coloquei esta lista também no meu outro blog, Theyself O, Lord, no qual escrevo mais sobre questões sociais.

Agora é planejar a leitura.

Doutrina Social da Igreja

Boniface VIII
Unam Sanctam
John XXII
Quum inter nonnullos


Nicholas V
Romanus Pontifex
Paul III
Sublimus Dei

Pius VII
Diu Satis
Leo XII
Quo Graiora


  Eugene IV
  Sicut Dudum 

  Clement XIV
  Decet Quam Maxime

  Pius VIII
  Traditi Humilitati

Gregory XVI

Cum Primum Mirari Vos Commissum Divinitus
In Supremo Apostolatus

Blessed Pius IX

Praedecessores Nostros Nostis et Nobiscum
Apostolicae Nostrae Caritatis
• Nullis Certe Verbis 
 • Quanto Conficiamur Moerore
 • Quanta CuraIncredibiliMaximae Quidem Respicientes
Etsi MultaQuod Nunquam Graves Ac Diuturnae

Blessed Leo XIII

Inscrutabili Dei Consilio Quod Apostolici Muneris • Licet Multa 
 • Diuturnum Cum Multa
Humanum Genus Nobilissima Gallorum Gens • Spectata Fides
Immortale DeiQuod Multum
 • In Plurimis LibertasSaepe Nos Quam Aerumnosa 
 • Sapientiae Christianae
Dall’Alto dell’Apostolico SeggioCatholicae Ecclesiae
Rerum Novarum
 • Au Milieu des Sollicitudes 
 • Custodi di Quella FedeInimica Vis 
 • LonginquaPermoti Nos 
 • Affari Vos • Testem Benevolentiae Nostrae 
 • Graves de Communi Re

Pope St. Pius X

Il Fermo Proposito Vehementer Nos Gravissimo Officii Munere
Une Fois Encore
Iamdudum
• Singulari Quadam

Benedict XV

Paterno Iam DiuAnnus Iam Plenus

Pius XI

Ubi Arcano Dei Consilio • Iniquis AffictisqueDivini Illius Magistri
Rappresentanti In Terra
Casti ConnubiiQuadragesimo Anno
Nova ImpendetNon Abbiamo Bisogno • Acerba Animi
Dilectissima NobisVigilanti Cura
Mit Brennender Sorge Divini Redemptoris
 • Nos Es Muy Conocida

Pius XII

Summi Pontificatus • QuemadmodumHumani Generis
• Ad Sinarum Gentem
Datis Nuperrime
Le Pèlerinage de LourdesMiranda Prorus
Ad Apostolorum PrincipisExsul Familia
On Rural Life

Blessed John XXIII

Mater et Magistra Pacem in Terris

Paul VI

Mense MaioChristi MatriPopulorum ProgressioHumanae Vitae
Octagesima Adveniens

John Paul II

Laborem ExercensSolicitudo Rei SocialisCentesimus Annus 
Veritatis Splendor 
Evangelium Vitae

Benedict XVI

Deus Caritas EstCaritas in Veritate

Distributismo

G.K. Chesterton

What’s Wrong with the World
The Outline of Sanity
Utopia of Usurers
Eugenics and Other Evils

Hilaire Belloc

The Servile State
An Essay on the Restoration of Property
The Way Out

Fr. Vincent McNabb

The Church and the Land
Nazareth or Social Chaos
Old Principles and the New Order
The Catholic Land Movement

Hilary Pepler (or St. Dominic’s Press)

Justice and the Child
The Devil’s Devices

G.C. Heseltine

Town to Country
The Change
Flee to the Fields by The Catholic Land Movement
The Fairy Ring of Commerce by Cmdr. Herbert Shove
The Sun of Justice by Harold Robbins

Arthur J. Penty

Guilds, Trade, and Agriculture
The Restoration of the Gild System
A Guildsman’s Interpretation of History
Guilds and the Social Crisis
Old Worlds for New
Post-Industrialism
Protection and Free Trade

 

Neo-Distributism

E.F. Schumacher

Good Work
A Guide for the Perplexed
Small is Beautiful
Mondragón Cooperative and Fr. José María Arizmendiarrieta
El otro Don José María
El hombre cooperativo: Pensamiento de Arizmendiarrieta †

Aleksandr Solzhenitsyn

Rebuilding Russia
Letter to Soviet Leaders
From Under the Rubble
Warning to the West
Solzhenitsyn’s 1978 Harvard Address

 

Solidarism

Fr. Heinrich Pesch, S.J.

Ethics and the National Economy
Lehrbuch Der Nationalokonomie

Dr. Rupert Ederer

Heinrich Pesch on Solidarist Economics
Economics As if God Mattered

Fr. Joseph Husslein, S.J.

Democratic Industry
The Church and Social Problems
The Catholic’s Work in the World
The World Problem: Capital, Labor, and the Church
Work, Wealth, Wages, and the Church

Msgr. John A. Ryan

Distributive Justice
The Living Wage
The State and the Church
A Catechism of the Social Question
Socialism: Promise or Menace?

Fr. John F. Cronin, S.J.

Communism: Threat to Freedom
The Church and the Working Man

Msgr. Luigi Civardi

How Christ Changed the World
A Concise Manual of Catholic Action

Msgr. Luigi Ligutti

Rural Roads to Security

Amintore Fanfani

Catholicism, Protestantism, and Capitalism

Archbishop Fulton J. Sheen

Philosophies at War

Leitura Adicional

A Message for Wall Street Protestors
An Introduction to Distributism by John Médaille
What is Distributism? by Thomas Storck
Reading List/FAQ from The Society for Distributism
Brochure from The Society for Distributism
Distributism: A Catholic System of Economics published by Goretti Publications
Distributism and Modern Economics published by Goretti Publications
The Distributism Debate published by Goretti Publications

quinta-feira, 27 de dezembro de 2012

Crematística e Economia

-

Crematística é a busca incessante por dinheiro, por acumulação de riqueza. Foi definida por Aristóteles. Será que é nisto que se tornou a economia, podemos definir a economia como a busca incessante por dinheiro? Tenho certeza que muitos economistas, especialmente aqueles do mercado financeiro, achariam uma boa definição, afinal o que importa é ganhar cada vez mais e ser o mais rico. Parecem o Gollum do filme Senhor dos Anéis (foto acima).

Abaixo vai um texto de Anthony Esolen da revista Crisis Magazine, costumo gostar muito dos textos dele. Neste artigo ele menciona crematística para discutir a importância do casamento.

Healthy Societies Need Successful Marriages



The great error of most economic thinking these days is not that it is too keenly focused on the economy, but that it has all but forgotten it.  A good friend of mine, a wise theologian, has encouraged his students to distinguish between what Aristotle calls chrematistics, the craft of amassing wealth, which Aristotle viewed with a healthy suspicion, and economics, the laws governing the management of an oikos, a household.  Another way to put this is that man is not made for an economy, but economy is made for man, who is ineluctably a social being, or, as Aristotle put it, a political being.

Aristotle did not mean that man is made for the ridiculous charade of self-government that we Americans enjoy every four years, with its heaves of moronic marketing, evasion, and dishonesty. Aristotle is the pagan with the flat feet. He stands squarely on the ground of common things. A political animal is a rational creature who thrives best within a polis, a smallish community of people who do not suffer edicts from afar, but who adjust their civil laws to the laws of man’s nature, to secure amongst themselves the common good.

There’s a nice analogy to draw, between mass politics which overwhelms the polis, along with its ally in mass “economics” or chrematistics whether of the left or the right, which ignores what man is made for, and society properly conceived, fashioned by healthy and thriving households.  Catholic Social Teaching will not allow us the ease of abstraction, as if “society” could denote any aggregate of human beings organized (or disorganized) according to any financial and, for want of a better word, political laws whatsoever.  In short, a society must be social—it must be based upon the human good of friendship and what the medieval English called “neighborhood,” meaning the virtue of getting along with and assisting those among whom we live most closely.  An economy, too, must be economic—it must be based on the good of households, and must aim, though in sometimes an intricate or circuitous way, at that same good.

We cannot make any headway understanding the encyclicals of Pope Leo XIII unless we keep these things firmly in mind.  The Pope’s teachings on the nature of man, his eternal destiny, the sanctity of marriage, the good of the family, and social and economic justice are all one coherent and harmonious vision.  So then let us turn to his encyclical on Christian marriage, Arcanum divinae (1880), for this too is eminently a social letter.

Leo begins by observing that Christ came among us, as Saint Paul says, “to re-establish all things” in Him—all things, not just the Sunday things, as it were.  Just as, in Aeterni patris, Leo affirmed the assistance that faith lends to reason, elevating it to heights it could never have scaled on its own, while reason in turn clarifies faith and protects it from lapsing into error, so too this new instauration in Christ “imparted a new form and fresh beauty to all things, taking away the effects of their time-worn age.”  That refreshment came in the order of nature, too, redounding to the good of nations and families.  “The authority of rulers,” he writes, “became more just and revered; the obedience of the people more ready and unforced; the union of citizens closer; the rights of dominion more secure.”  Indeed, the Christian faith could hardly have done more to procure the truly good things of a common life, had it been instituted solely for that purpose.

Such is the context for Leo’s discussion of marriage—and marriage, in turn, is the context for his economic and political thinking. The first thing he insists upon is that marriage is not a human creation, much less a creation of the State, but is of divine origin. Its fruition is not in the satisfaction of individual desires, as potent or as harmless as some of those may be. It is, because it is divine, by necessity oriented towards the being of God Himself. Its fruitfulness participates in His creative bounty. Its unity reflects the inner life of love that is the Trinity. Its exclusivity and perpetuity reflect His faithfulness and His eternity.

When Jesus teaches us that the two great commandments are like unto one another, we are apt to remember that we cannot love God aright unless we love our neighbor; but apt to forget that our love of neighbor cannot be divorced from the love we owe to God. If, then, we sin against marriage, demoting it to the status of a contract, which in pagan times could be abrogated by the husband at a whim (and which now can be so abrogated by either party), we sin against God and neighbor both. We sow dissolution in what should be a society but degenerates into a mass, an aggregate, a confounding of wills.

Thus, according to Leo, it was an act of the highest mercy and justice at once, when Jesus blessed marriage at Cana, and went on to bring back “matrimony to the nobility of its primeval origin,” in his role as “supreme Lawgiver.”  We misread things if we assume that only a prohibition against divorce is involved.  The marriage of man and woman, grounded in their biological, earthly nature, is divine in origin and end; it is the sphere in which most of us will be called to holiness, with a procreation both physical and spiritual: “By the command of Christ, [marriage] not only looks to the propagation of the human race, but to the bringing forth of children for the Church, fellow-citizens with the saints, and the domestics of God (Eph. 2:19).”  Leo is ever at pains to show that the Church does for the State what the State cannot well do for itself: she makes citizens of the city of God, citizens who make for something like a just city here below.

If we consider the matter carefully, we see not only that Christian marriage is the foundation for a genuine society.  It is a society in itself, and a model for the society at large.   Thus when Leo describes the inner dynamic of a Christian marriage, it is in social terms.  “The mutual duties of husband and wife have been defined,” he writes, “and their several rights accurately established.  They are bound, namely, to have such feelings for one another as to cherish always very great mutual love, to be ever faithful to their marriage vow, and to give one another an unfailing and unselfish help.”  The key words here are mutual and several.  They have profound implications for all genuine Catholic teaching on the just society.

We have almost lost the sense of gift implied by the word mutual.  For us, it means that if John does something, then Mary does the same, and so on, until the end of time.  We take it to imply a flat identity.  But the inner meaning of the word involves an exchange of gifts, a reciprocity that is not arithmetical but human.  Thus the mutuality of the love between husband and wife is implied in their several or separate, distinct duties.  It is precisely because the husband and wife are not the same in their mode of being human and even in their physical relations to one another that they can most fully embody the complete gift of self that love demands.  Each complements the other; each completes the other, and this completion is not subjective but an objective, incarnate fact.  The two are one flesh.  The man is for the woman, the woman for the man, and both, as individuals and as a married couple, are for God.

From Christian marriages, says Leo, “the State may rightly expect a race of citizens animated by a good spirit and filled with reverence and love for God, recognizing in it their duty to obey those who rule justly and lawfully, to love all, and to injure no one.”  What, by contrast, might we expect from an anti-society of self-will and divorce?  For some hedonists delight in riches, and others delight in sex, and still others in prestige or ease or hectic excitements.  Leo won’t mince words.  When Christian marriage is deprecated, man sinks “into the slavery of [his] vicious nature and vile passions,” and nothing, says Leo, “has such power to lay waste families and destroy the mainstay of kingdoms as the corruption of morals.”  Or are we to believe that men who are shameless and shiftless in the most intimate and most socially productive of human relations will, in any great numbers, be animated by civic responsibility and love of neighbor in their other public actions, where their duties are less clear, and the opportunities for self-serving almost limitless?

Every sin against marriage is a sin against the very possibility of any kind of society at all.  Every Christian marriage begun in purity and continued in faithfulness and duty and love is an exemplar for all social relations, and allows us to imagine something better than the loneliness of self-will “wedded,” in ghastly symbiosis, to the inhumanity of economics without households, and a state without citizens.

segunda-feira, 3 de dezembro de 2012

Capitalismo protege Ricos, assim com o Socialismo


Publiquei este post originalmente no meu outro blog (Thyself, O Lord), porque o assunto ultrapassa a questão econômica.

Um dos maiores defeitos do capitalismo, o socialismo não oferece cura, é a defesa ados privilegiados. Há sempre uma turma de privilegiados nos dois modos de produção. Os dois gráficos abaixo mostram este defeito do capitalismo.

Os Estados Unidos estão em crise desde 2008, o pais mantém uma taxa de desemprego próxima de 8%, o que está bem acima da média hsitórica do país, a dívida pública já é maior do que o PIB (Obama pegou o estoque da dívida em 10 trilhões e aumentou em 6 trilhões em menos de quatro anos), e o crescimento econômico é vacilante (por volta de 1,5%). Obama tem uma pívia média de crescimento econômico nos anos de seu governo. Além disso, a capacidade de negociação do Obama com o Congresso é medíocre, e o país corre o risco de enfrentar o chamado "abismo fiscal" (aumento de impostos e corte de gastos) no próximo ano, se eles não entrarem em um acordo este mês.

Mas com todo este cenário, o lucro das empresas bate recorde de alta nos Estados Unidos, enquanto a participação dos salários na economia americana bate recorde de baixa. Isto é, as empresas estão protegendo suas margens de lucro da crise econômica, enquanto demitem gente.

É o que mostram os dois gráficos do site Business Insider.

1) Lucro das empresas sobre PIB


2) Participação dos salários na economia:



O capitalismo sozinho não cura a pobreza, há necessidade de que questões morais e sociais sejam executadas pelas pessoas. Não devem ser impostas pelo governo, pois isso provoca apenas a fuga das empresas e se cria um novo grupo de privilegiados. É uma questão de educação e moral cristã.


(Agradeço os dois gráficos ao site New Advent)

domingo, 2 de dezembro de 2012

Como nasceu o Euro?

-





Texto de Raymond Zhong no Wall Street Jorunal recomenda o livro acima de Harold James, que fala do processo de formação da União Européia. Pareceu bem interessante pelas vertentes política e cultural que parecem conter o livro.

Leiam o texto de Zhong abaixo:

Follow the Money 

The euro was the product of more than a dozen committees and governmental bodies that met hundreds of times over a period of 40 years. Each involved representatives of as many as 12 European nation-states, many of which had met each other in battle not long before. A single currency wasn't the project's original objective, as Harold James notes in his meticulous account of their deliberations, and as Europe crept its way toward the introduction of the euro in 1999, policy makers' steely resolve to build a new continent ran up against their inability to get along. Reading "Making the European Monetary Union," it seems miraculous that anything came out of the process at all.

Mr. James, a historian at Princeton, begins with the 1957 creation of the European Economic Community (EEC), a customs union between six Western European states, and concludes with the 1992 Maastricht Treaty, which set the stage for a common currency. But the impetus for European monetary integration began earlier. Under the Bretton Woods system, created in 1944 as the basis of a postwar monetary order, participant countries were obliged to accumulate reserves to maintain a stable exchange rate against the U.S. dollar. Washington thus enjoyed the "exorbitant privilege," as French finance minister Valéry Giscard d'Estaing called it in 1965, of using monetary policy to stimulate its domestic economy while partner countries were forced to match the flood of dollars with monetary expansion of their own, in order to prevent speculative runs on their currencies.

At the same time, economic imbalances within Europe produced tensions among member countries. West Germany became an industrial power in the late 1950s and began to run persistent current-account surpluses. This forced its trading partners to apply fiscal brakes to defend the value of their currencies. Such measures were anathema in free-spending France—a rift that divides Europe still. Mr. James quotes Raymond Barre, the French vice president of the EEC Commission, advising Germany to take "energetic measures for speedier growth and the stimulation of imports." That was in 1968, but it could easily be today.

A series of crises in the EEC provoked experiments in integration. Inflation in the 1970s, after the Bretton Woods regime crumbled, convinced European leaders that monetary policy could be a stabilizing force. In 1979, after an attempt at loosely linking European exchange rates failed, the European Monetary System was introduced, in which a weighted basket of European currencies served as the unit of account. But this too fell prey to speculative attacks, as markets doubted that squabbling politicians could hold the system together.

By the end of the 1980s, European decision makers concluded that the internal anchor of price stability was more easily enforced than the external anchor of exchange rates. Germany's central bankers had held such hard-money values all along, of course, and Mr. James's book allows one to see that the overarching narrative of the half-century is one of the intellectual tide across Europe moving in the Bundesbank's direction. The Spanish and Italian governments had come to see monetary union—and the attendant interest-rate convergence with Germany—as a way to save money on their borrowing costs. François Mitterrand ceded the French Republic's grip on the Banque de France once he realized that Paris could exercise political influence over European monetary policy only from within the new, "Germanic" system. It was a conversion, not a surrender.

The value of "Making the European Monetary Union" is in showing how these ideological swerves played out in real meeting rooms, with real finance ministers, central bankers and heads of government. Commissioned by the Bank for International Settlements and the European Central Bank (ECB), the book benefits from unprecedented access to both institutions' archives. Mr. James's fly-on-the-wall accounts of committee meetings and central-bank deliberations offer illuminating detail about how the precise wording of important agreements came to be decided.

A 1990 meeting of the EEC Monetary Committee, for instance, saw a debate on whether it should be an "objective" of the new system of European central banks to "preserve the integrity of the financial system." Bundesbank board member Hans Tietmeyer said it should be a "task," not an "objective." Eventually it was agreed, at Germany's urging, that the new system wouldn't act as a classical lender of last resort. "Preserve" became "support"; "integrity" became "stability." In the final ECB statute, Article 3 "tasks" the central banks "to promote the smooth operation of payment systems."

Europe finally agreed to go ahead with a single currency and a single monetary policy in 1992. "The most fundamental problems of European coordination—exchange rate and monetary policy issues—were solved as it were by the waving of a wand," Mr. James writes. But were they really? European borrowing costs of course converged under the ECB's single monetary policy. The question ought to have been why: Did banks and investors in the 2000s buy Spanish debt at German rates because they expected Spain's economy to become more like Germany's—or because they expected the euro zone to bail Spain out in the event of a crisis? As it turned out, payments imbalances that previously showed up in exchange rates and central-bank reserves instead showed up as misdirected investment: blowout public spending in Greece and Portugal, housing bubbles in Spain and Ireland. Europe failed to enforce its fiscal rules simply because it was "hard to imagine that balance-of-payments problems would arise in a monetary union," Mr. James writes.

"Making the European Monetary Union" is a book for wonks. Anyone not already well-versed in economics will find it hard going. But Mr. James has produced a valuable companion to today's headlines, a comprehensive primer on how Europe got to its unhappy state. My take-away is that the highly imperfect euro that resulted may be the only euro that a politically dysfunctional and economically unbalanced Europe could have produced. Reading the book is like watching a horror film whose ending you know in advance. At every turn, you want to cry out, Stop!